View other editions of the ezine here

Issue 23/19 May 2010

Anforme Limited has published Economics books and resources for A Level and IB since 1977. For our catalogue go to: www.anforme.com

You are free to use these articles by printing them or putting them on your school intranet. We only ask that you keep our copyright and web details at the end of each article.

This edition is going to economics teachers and students in 45 countries


Today’s Issue Includes:


1) Chancellor announces revolution in UK fiscal policy by Nigel Tree

nigelcropforezineIntroduction
On Monday 17th May, the Chancellor George Osborne, introduced a major change in the way UK fiscal policy would be enacted in future. If Gordon Brown could revolutionise monetary policy a week after Labour came to power in 1997 by giving independence to the Bank of England to target interest rates, then the Conservative led coalition was not to be outdone. It has set up the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR) under the chairmanship of Sir Alan Budd.

What was the previous fiscal framework?
The fiscal framework introduced in 1997 was specified in the Code for Fiscal Stability. Under the provisions of this Code, the government set two fiscal rules, which were the Golden Rule and the Sustainable Investment Rule.

The Golden Rule stated that over the economic cycle the government would borrow only to invest and not to fund current spending. The Sustainable Investment Rule required the government to keep debt at a "prudent level" which was set at below 40% of GDP in each year of the current cycle.

The Code stated that in each Budget Report, the government had to provide “an economic and fiscal projection, an explanation of significant fiscal policy measures introduced in the Budget, and an explanation, where necessary, of how these policy measures restore the path of the public finances to a position consistent with the fiscal policy … rules.”

The decision as to whether the government’s tax and spending decsions were sufficient to place it on track to meet its fiscal rules was based on the fiscal projections made in the Budget for borrowing and debt. These forecasts were made by the Chancellor on the basis of macroeconomic and fiscal analysis and advice produced by the Treasury.

Why is the new government unhappy with the previous regime?
According to the Chancellor’s statement: “The potential incentive to optimistically forecast lower borrowing and higher growth, and so delay necessary measures to strengthen the public finances, led to scepticism over the credibility of the Government’s forecasts. Budget forecasts over the last decade consistently underestimated borrowing, compared to both outturn and independent forecasts made at the time.”

The evidence produced maintains that all forecasts for borrowing for more than one year ahead since Budget 2000 have underestimated borrowing. It is claimed that the average one year ahead forecast was 0.4% of GDP lower than the outturn between Budget 2000 and Budget 2009, with average 5 year ahead forecasts 3.5% of GDP lower than outturn, equal to £52bn in today’s prices.

It is noted that the government’s forecasts for borrowing in the medium term have consistently been below those of independent external forecasters. Also, the Budget 2010 forecast for growth is above the average of independent forecasts whilst the forecast for borrowing is below the independent average.

How will the new regime work?
The newly-created OBR will make an independent assessment of the public finances and the economy for the upcoming emergency Budget. This will be the first time that forecasts will not be determined by the judgement of the Chancellor. It is claimed that the “independence of the OBR’s judgements will ensure that policy is made on an unbiased view of future prospects, improving confidence in the fiscal forecasts.”

The Chancellor will retain responsibility for fiscal policy and will set the ‘fiscal mandate’, his target for fiscal policy. The Treasury will provide the OBR with full access to all necessary data to scrutinise the public finances.

In each Budget and Pre-Budget Report the OBR will confirm whether the government’s policy is consistent with a better than 50% chance of achieving the forward looking fiscal target set by the Chancellor. This, it is claimed, will improve the quality of fiscal policy-making.

The OBR will be established on a permanent, statutory basis through subsequent legislation which will be introduced in the Queen’s Speech.

Sir Alan Budd summed up by saying: “It is quite remarkable that the chancellor has given us the authority to produce independent forecasts for the Budget and Pre-Budget Report and to provide a public assessment of the action needed to achieve his fiscal mandate:”

He said: “We are not claiming that we shall get the fiscal forecasts right; it is easy to demonstrat that that is impossible. Above all, we shall be emphasising the risks and uncertainties; but every judgement will be ours and we guarantee the independence and integrity of our work. We shall also increase the transparency of the forecasting process. We hope that the result will be greater credibility and an improvement in the quality of the fiscal decisions that will have to be made.”

Conclusion
In setting out these new arrangements George Osborne also announced plans for £6 billion of spending cuts to tackle the government deficit this year, although they haven’t been assigned yet. The government claims that this can be done in a way that will not reduce the quality of public services. However, there is already talk of NHS trusts cutting back on front-line staff to balance their books.

So what of the new Office for Budget Responsibility? On the surface it seems a decent measure. The Chancellor didn’t exactly mention that the “books were being cooked” by the previous government but implied it all the same using polite language. There has certainly been a deviation between government fiscal forecasts and the independent forecasts provided by independent economic analysts, and a system of independent forecasting and improved scrutiny is surely to be welcomed.


Revision time is here. Now is the time to get hold of our 2 bestselling revision books for AS and A2. Click on the covers for more information.

revision-guide-cover_01 revisionguidetoa2leveleconomicsforwebjpg

Top


2) Fiscal crisis, contagion, and the future of the euro by Marco Pagano, Professor of Economics, University of Naples Federico II and CEPR Research Fellow

paganoThe Eurozone has been swept up in turmoil that has ranged from stock and bond markets to exchange rates, government spending, and tax rates. Marco Pagano, Professor at the University of Naples Federico II and CEPR Research Fellow, explains events, how they hang together, and what needs to be done. This challenge facing Europe could be a historical turning point.

Fiscal crisis, contagion, breakdown of the euro... Let’s try to understand what is going on. In the past few days, the scenarios discussed in the media have been changing so rapidly and dramatically that for many it may be hard to grasp the reason behind them. But in emergencies such as the one we are currently experiencing, the way to escape the worst-case scenarios and find an exit strategy is to stick to clear-headed thinking.

What happens when sovereign states accumulate large debts?
First, investors start worrying that this debt may not be sustainable: concerns rise over the ability of the state to pay back capital and interests by generating budget surpluses in the future (that is, fiscal revenues in excess of expenditures). In this case, investors require higher interest rates to subscribe new public debt as a compensation for the risk of insolvency. This in turn increases the risk of insolvency as it worsens public sector balance sheets. At some point, there may no longer be an interest rate able to compensate investors for the risk of insolvency; then they just stop subscribing the public debt. This is a situation of fiscal crisis and has only two possible (and not mutually exclusive) outcomes:
1.government default followed by a renegotiation of the debt (as in Argentina’s case),
2.monetisation of the debt, which is effectively bought by the central bank. This represents an injection of money in the economy and thus generates inflation and exchange-rate depreciation.

From Greece to Italy

Second, in the case of Greece, the second option – monetisation - was ruled out by Greece’s membership in the European monetary union: the Greek government could not force the ECB to buy its own bonds. For this reason, the only option was insolvency and renegotiation of the debt, unless other countries were willing to lend to Greece at an interest rate lower than the market rate. Why did euro-area countries choose to do so? In the past few days it has been clear that, following a substantial dose of indecision, they did it mainly for fear of “contagion"

But what is contagion?

Here we come to the third and most interesting part of the story. As the Greek crisis unfolded, investors started to suspect that other countries with high levels of public debt, namely Portugal, Spain and Italy, would find themselves in a similar situation. But as governments of these countries rushed to point out, their fiscal position is not as dramatic as the Greek one.

So why are investors so concerned? Because, as economists say, in this game between sovereign states and investors there can be “multiple equilibria”. Even if the government is not highly indebted, investors might start questioning its willingness to raise taxes above a level considered “politically sustainable”. In the future, it might seek a renegotiation of the debt, its monetisation, or both. Fear that this will happen can push interest rates to a level so high that the investors’ prophecy will eventually come true. At the prevailing interest rates a country which would have otherwise been able to service its debt ends up needing a renegotiation or a monetisation of the debt to avoid full repayment (see for example Calvo 1988).

So the outcome depends on investors’ confidence. If there is confidence, the “good equilibrium” with moderate interest rates and stable markets prevails; when confidence disappears, the economy jumps to a “bad equilibrium”, where a fiscal crisis occurs. The contagion generated by Greek crisis has been exactly of this type. It has weakened investors’ confidence in countries which would have otherwise been in a safe situation. Moreover, the burden of Greek bail-out itself is affecting negatively the fiscal position of Portugal, Spain, and Italy. This too may have contributed to weaken confidence in their ability to service the debt.

Stock exchanges and speculation

The fourth element that has played a role in the crisis is “roll-over risk”. Countries involved are exposed to a fiscal crisis (the “bad equilibrium”) to the extent that they are forced to rely on the market to roll-over their debt. Thus, much depends on the amount of public debt coming to maturity in the next months. This in turn depends on the maturity structure of the public debt. If public debt mainly has a long-term maturity, then the amount of debt to be rolled-over in a certain time interval is small and the burden of a high interest rate might be sustainable. In these cases, the risk of a fiscal crisis is ruled out. If instead the debt has mainly a short-term maturity so that the amount to be rolled-over is large, then a fiscal crisis can occur, as illustrated in my paper with Francesco Giavazzi (Giavazzi and Pagano 1988). The argument is similar to the one used by banks to assess companies’ solvency. There, the roll-over risk arising from short-term maturity debt is one of the main factors in determining bankruptcy risk.

Why is the euro depreciating?

Fifth, in the last few days we have witnessed the sudden depreciation of the euro. Why is the euro depreciating? A possible answer is that as the crisis spreads to other large Eurozone countries, the risk of monetisation of the public debt becomes more concrete. Even if Greece can be bailed out by other countries in the Eurozone, this would not be feasible for the much larger public debts of Italy, Spain, and Portugal. In the scenario of a widespread crisis, the possibility that the ECB will monetise the debt of weak Eurozone countries exists, and fear of the implied inflation can explain the depreciation of the euro. However, a massive monetisation is an unlikely scenario, as it would eventually undermine price stability in the Eurozone and imply a substantial transfer of resources from strong to weak Eurozone countries.

A breakdown in the euro?

An alternative explanation for the depreciation of the euro is the fear of a breakdown of the single currency itself, a scenario that was unthinkable even a few months ago. In order to avoid having to bail-out weak Eurozone countries through debt monetisation, the strong countries might push the weak ones outside the Eurozone. Obviously, this would be a dramatic scenario, as redrawing the borders of the common currency could hardly happen without generating a financial earthquake. Meanwhile, such a crisis could degenerate into the insolvency on the public debt of several Eurozone countries, with devastating effects on the global economy. Given that the public debt of these countries is massively present in the balance sheets of banks and insurance companies all over the world, and in the Eurozone in particular, instability would spread throughout the financial system. Contagion would become really global. In comparison, the sub-prime crisis would almost pale into insignificance (see a similar discussion in Eichengreen 2007).

This explains why last week stock exchanges collapsed and why governments on both sides of the Atlantic are very concerned. However, governments’ invectives against speculators and markets are childish. The word “speculator” comes from the Latin word “specula” (watchtower) and indicates someone who tries to “look far away” and thus metaphorically “look ahead”, in other words to foresee future events. Whenever a saver decides whether to subscribe public debt bonds he also tries to “look ahead” and, in this sense, we are all speculators. And we all contribute to determine market outcomes, even when we decide to abstain from participating in them. Rather than blaming them, governments have to demonstrate that speculators and markets got their forecasts and bets wrong.

Restoring market confidence

Can the markets’ confidence be restored? As the origin of the problem lies in fiscal policy, confidence needs to be re-established there: strong and coordinated signals must be sent about the ability of the weak states in the Eurozone to put their fiscal situation in order, accepting the imposition of strong monitoring and discipline on fiscal policy by the Union’s institutions.

This implies a significant limitation on the fiscal sovereignty of member states, which comes on top of their delegation of monetary sovereignty to the ECB. But much more is needed than the fragile discipline imposed by the Maastricht treaty and by the stability pact, such as binding constraints on budget laws of member states and institutions able to enforce them.
It is not an easy task. Such a monitoring and enforcement system is difficult to put in place and politically painful to accept, as the riots and deaths in Athens demonstrate. Will governments and national parliaments be willing to do it? If the answer is “yes”, then Europe will re-emerge stronger from this crisis and will move toward completing its supranational structure with the gradual introduction of fiscal federal institutions, the natural counterpart of the ECB.

This may also offer the opportunity to finally fill the “democratic deficit” of the EU, since it is natural that binding fiscal decisions be taken by representative political bodies. In this way, the necessary limits to national fiscal sovereignty would not be seen as coming from the diktat of some technical and bureaucratic organism or ministers’ committee, as they have a supranational democratic legitimacy. If Eurozone countries have the courage to embrace this great challenge, not only will confidence be restored on security markets, but this crisis will become the occasion for a historical turning point in the development of Europe as political entity.

References

Calvo, Guillermo (1988), “Servicing the Public Debt: The Role of Expectations”, American EconomicReview,September.
Eichengreen, Barry (2007), “The euro: love it or leave it?”, VoxEU.org, 17 November.
Francesco Giavazzi and Marco Pagano (1988), “The Management of Public Debt and Financial Markets,” in L Spaventa and F Giavazzi (eds.), High Public Debt: the Italian Experience, Cambridge University Press.

Copyright VoxEU.org

Top


To see a full range of our economics books, posters and other resources go to: www.anforme.com

To see previous ezines and blogs just go to our home page and click on the appropriate buttons at www.anforme.com

Copyright Anforme Limited


Visit the Anforme website